For all those who...
For all those who...
For all those who still believe in Keynesian Economics:
Have you ever witnessed the anger of the good shopkeeper, James B.,
when his careless son happened to break a square of glass? If you have
been present at such a scene, you will most assuredly bear witness to
the fact, that every one of the spectators, were there even thirty of
them, by common consent apparently, offered the unfortunate owner this
invariable consolation - "It is an ill wind that blows nobody good.
Everybody must live, and what would become of the glaziers if panes of
glass were never broken?"
Now, this form of condolence contains
an entire theory, which it will be well to show up in this simple case,
seeing that it is precisely the same as that which, unhappily,
regulates the greater part of our economical institutions.
Suppose it cost six francs to repair the damage, and you say that the
accident brings six francs to the glazier's trade - that it encourages
that trade to the amount of six francs - I grant it; I have not a word
to say against it; you reason justly. The glazier comes, performs his
task, receives his six francs, rubs his hands, and, in his heart,
blesses the careless child. All this is that which is seen.
But
if, on the other hand, you come to the conclusion, as is too often the
case, that it is a good thing to break windows, that it causes money to
circulate, and that the encouragement of industry in general will be the
result of it, you will oblige me to call out, "Stop there! your theory
is confined to that which is seen; it takes no account of that which is
not seen."
It is not seen that as our shopkeeper has spent six
francs upon one thing, he cannot spend them upon another. It is not seen
that if he had not had a window to replace, he would, perhaps, have
replaced his old shoes, or added another book to his library. In short,
he would have employed his six francs in some way, which this accident
has prevented.
Let us take a view of industry in general, as
affected by this circumstance. The window being broken, the glazier's
trade is encouraged to the amount of six francs; this is that which is
seen. If the window had not been broken, the shoemaker's trade (or some
other) would have been encouraged to the amount of six francs; this is
that which is not seen.
And if that which is not seen is taken
into consideration, because it is a negative fact, as well as that which
is seen, because it is a positive fact, it will be understood that
neither industry in general, nor the sum total of national labour, is
affected, whether windows are broken or not.
Now let us
consider James B. himself. In the former supposition, that of the window
being broken, he spends six francs, and has neither more nor less than
he had before, the enjoyment of a window.
In the second, where
we suppose the window not to have been broken, he would have spent six
francs on shoes, and would have had at the same time the enjoyment of a
pair of shoes and of a window.
Now, as James B. forms a part of
society, we must come to the conclusion, that, taking it altogether,
and making an estimate of its enjoyments and its labours, it has lost
the value of the broken window.
When we arrive at this
unexpected conclusion: "Society loses the value of things which are
uselessly destroyed;" and we must assent to a maxim which will make the
hair of protectionists stand on end - To break, to spoil, to waste, is
not to encourage national labour; or, more briefly, "destruction is not
profit."
What will you say, Monsieur Industriel -- what will
you say, disciples of good M. F. Chamans, who has calculated with so
much precision how much trade would gain by the burning of Paris, from
the number of houses it would be necessary to rebuild?
I am
sorry to disturb these ingenious calculations, as far as their spirit
has been introduced into our legislation; but I beg him to begin them
again, by taking into the account that which is not seen, and placing it
alongside of that which is seen. The reader must take care to remember
that there are not two persons only, but three concerned in the little
scene which I have submitted to his attention. One of them, James B.,
represents the consumer, reduced, by an act of destruction, to one
enjoyment instead of two. Another under the title of the glazier, shows
us the producer, whose trade is encouraged by the accident. The third is
the shoemaker (or some other tradesman), whose labour suffers
proportionably by the same cause. It is this third person who is always
kept in the shade, and who, personating that which is not seen, is a
necessary element of the problem. It is he who shows us how absurd it is
to think we see a profit in an act of destruction. It is he who will
soon teach us that it is not less absurd to see a profit in a
restriction, which is, after all, nothing else than a partial
destruction. Therefore, if you will only go to the root of all the
arguments which are adduced in its favour, all you will find will be the
paraphrase of this vulgar saying - What would become of the glaziers,
if nobody ever broke windows?
No comments:
Post a Comment