Proposals to adopt single-payer health care in the United
States have grown in popularity in recent years, as numerous lawmakers
and presidential candidates have embraced Medicare for All. However, few
have grappled with how to finance the new costs imposed on the federal
government. By most estimates, Medicare for All would cost the federal
government about $30 trillion over the next decade. How this cost is
financed would have considerable distributional, economic, and policy
implications.
In the coming months, the Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget
will publish a detailed analysis describing numerous ways to finance
Medicare for All and the consequences and trade-offs associated with
each choice. This paper provides our
preliminary estimates of
the magnitude of each potential change and a brief discussion of the
types of trade-offs policymakers will need to consider.
We find that Medicare for All could be financed with:
A 32 percent payroll tax
A 25 percent income surtax
A 42 percent value-added tax (VAT)
A mandatory public premium
averaging $7,500 per capita – the equivalent of $12,000 per individual
not otherwise on public insurance
More than doubling all individual and corporate income tax rates
An 80 percent reduction in non-health federal spending
A 108 percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) increase in the national debt
Impossibly high taxes on high earners, corporations, and the financial sector
A combination of approaches
Each of these choices would have consequences for the distribution of
income, growth in the economy, and ability to raise new revenue. Some
of these consequences could be balanced against each other by adopting a
combination approach that includes smaller versions of several of the
options as well as additional policies.
Consequences could also be mitigated through aggressive efforts to
lower per-person health care costs and/or by substantially scaling back
the generosity or comprehensiveness of Medicare for All.
The Cost of Medicare for All
Though it is a somewhat amorphous term, the term Medicare for All has
come to represent proposals that offer universal, single-payer health
insurance coverage for virtually all health care services (including
dental, vision, and long-term care) with no meaningful premiums,
deductibles, copayments, or restrictive networks.
In theory, Medicare for All may increase or decrease national health
expenditures, which is the total amount spent on health care by all
private and public sources. Cost increases would come from covering
those who are currently uninsured; expanding coverage to include
services like dental, vision, and long-term care; and eliminating
deductibles and copayments that currently help curb utilization. Cost
reductions would come from lower administrative costs and significantly
lower payments to medical providers and drug manufacturers.
Regardless of the impact on total national health expenditures,
adopting Medicare for All would mean shifting virtually all private
health costs to the federal government. Most independent estimates of
Medicare for All find it would cost the federal government $25 trillion
to $36 trillion over ten years (though not all incorporate long-term
care coverage). Most recently, the
Urban Institute
estimated Medicare for All would cost $34 trillion over the next
decade, or $32 trillion net of income tax effects. These estimates
represent additional costs on top of the $16 trillion the federal
government is already projected to spend on major health programs over
the next decade.
The bulk of this expense represents the direct cost of eliminating
premiums, copayments, and other out-of-pocket costs. That spending will
total nearly $2 trillion this year alone. Replacing it will require
significant new funds regardless of changes to national health
expenditures.
Options for Financing Medicare for All
For the purpose of our analysis, we assume Medicare for All would
cost $30 trillion over the next decade net of new revenue – roughly the
midpoint of a variety of estimates. Though much of this cost represents
savings to the private sector, it nonetheless needs to be financed
through higher taxes, lower spending, more borrowing, or some
combination of the three.
Our estimates are rough and preliminary, do not account for economic
feedback, and may change modestly in our final analysis. Importantly,
the options we present are illustrative rather than prescriptive. Their
economic, distributional, and other consequences should be weighed
relative to each other and against the effects of eliminating all
premiums and out-of-pocket spending and providing comprehensive,
universal health coverage through the federal government.
We estimate that policymakers could finance Medicare for All over the next decade in any of the following ways:
1
Impose a 32 percent payroll tax.
Currently, most wage income is subject to a 15.3 percent payroll tax
divided evenly between workers and employers to fund Social Security and
Medicare. Wages above $133,000 are subject to either a 2.9 percent or
3.8 percent payroll tax to fund Medicare. We estimate a new 32 percent
payroll tax, divided evenly between workers and employers, would raise
roughly $30 trillion over a decade. This tax would apply to all wages,
not just those below a taxable maximum. An equivalent amount of revenue
could be raised with a 23 percent payroll tax on the employee side only
or a 48 percent tax on the employer side.
2
A 32 percent payroll tax would raise the total payroll tax rate on most
wage income to above 47 percent and the rate for high-wage earners to
nearly 36 percent. It would apply to all earned income.
Establish a 25 percent income surtax on adjusted gross income (AGI) above the standard deduction. Under
current law, households pay taxes on their income under a progressive
rate structure that ranges from 10 percent to 37 percent, with
preferential rates for long-term capital gains and qualified dividends
as well as deductions for mortgage interest, charitable giving, state
and local taxes up to $10,000, pass-through business income, and other
purposes. There is also a standard deduction of $12,200 for individuals
and $24,400 for married couples. We estimate a 25 percent income surtax
above the standard deduction threshold – which would apply to all AGI
without deductions or preferences – would raise roughly $30 trillion
over a decade.
3
This surtax would effectively increase the bottom income tax rate from
10 to 35 percent, the top income tax rate from 37 to 62 percent, and the
top capital gains and dividends rate from 24 to 49 percent.
Enact a 42 percent value-added tax (VAT). Whereas
most developed countries raise a substantial share of their revenue
through a tax on consumption – known as a VAT – the United States only
taxes consumption broadly through state and local sales taxes. A VAT
could be introduced at the federal level to finance Medicare for All.
Based on
estimates
from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), we project a broad-based
VAT of 42 percent would raise about $30 trillion over a decade. The
first-order effect of this VAT would be to increase the prices of most
goods and services by 42 percent; the VAT would thus represent 30
percent of costs on a tax-inclusive basis, which is more comparable to
an equivalent income or payroll tax rate increase. Importantly, a VAT
can be designed in a number of different ways, and a different tax base
would change the required tax rate.
Require a mandatory public premium
averaging $7,500 per capita – the equivalent of $12,000 per individual
not otherwise on public insurance. Currently, most Americans
are charged health insurance premiums – the majority of which are paid
by employers on their behalf. Though current Medicare for All proposals
call for ending premiums, policymakers could consider financing Medicare
for All through mandatory fixed-dollar payments to the federal
government. These payments would be a form of head tax but could
resemble premiums in a number of ways. For example, they could vary
based on household size and could be paid in part or in whole by
employers. They could also be reduced or waived for some individuals,
perhaps based on income. In 2021, we estimate those premiums would need
to average about $7,500 per capita or $20,000 per household (including
single-person households) and is the average applied to all individuals,
including retirees, children, and low-income individuals. As an
illustrative example, fully exempting everyone who would otherwise be on
Medicare, Medicaid, or CHIP would increase the premiums by over 60
percent to more than $12,000 per individual.
More than double all individual and corporate income tax rates.
Under current law, ordinary income is taxed under a progressive rate
structure with a bottom rate of 10 percent and a top rate of 37 percent,
while long-term capital gains and qualified dividends are taxed at a
top rate of 23.8 percent and corporate income at a rate of 21 percent.
Assuming capital gains are taxed at death and pass-through income is no
longer deductible,
4 we estimate that
doubling
all individual income tax rates would raise $20 trillion to $25
trillion over a decade, and doubling the corporate rate would raise
about $2 trillion. Some additional revenue would be needed on top of
these increases to reach $30 trillion in total revenue. This option
differs from the income surtax in a number of ways, especially because
it would represent a much smaller tax increase for lower-income
taxpayers. Under this scenario, the bottom ordinary income tax rate
would be raised to 20 percent, the top ordinary rate would be 74
percent, capital gains would be taxed at a top rate of 47.6 percent, and
the corporate tax rate would be 42 percent.
Reduce non-health federal spending by 80 percent.
The federal government is projected to spend $60 trillion over the next
decade, including $16 trillion on health care and $6 trillion on
interest costs. Accounting roughly for the taxation of certain federal
benefits, we estimate that financing the full cost of Medicare for All
with spending cuts would require cutting the remaining federal budget by
80 percent.
5
Cuts of this magnitude are unrealistically large and certainly could
not be imposed on a short timeline. For illustrative purposes, an 80
percent cut to Social Security would mean reducing the average new
benefit from about $18,000 per year to $3,600 per year, and an 80
percent cut to the military would mean, among other things, reducing the
number of soldiers and officers from about 1.3 million today to
270,000.
More than double the national debt to 205 percent of the economy. Federal
debt held by the public currently totals about $17 trillion, or 79
percent of GDP. Under current law, debt is projected to reach 97 percent
of GDP by 2030. Assuming no changes in projected interest rates or
economic growth, deficit-financing Medicare for All over the next decade
would require about $34 trillion of new borrowing including interest,
which is the equivalent of 108 percent of GDP by 2030. As a result, debt
would rise above 205 percent of GDP, more than double its currently
projected level. This would put debt in 2030 at almost five times its
historic average of 42 percent and nearly twice the historic record of
106 percent (set after World War II). Under this scenario, debt would
continue to grow rapidly beyond 2030.
Impose impossibly high taxes on high earners, corporations, and the financial sector. There
is not enough annual income available among higher earners to finance
the full cost of Medicare for All. On a static basis, even increasing
the top two income tax rates (applying to individuals making over
$204,000 per year and couples making over $408,000 per year) to 100
percent would not raise $30 trillion over a decade. In reality, a tax
increase that large would actually
lose revenue because it
would institute marginal tax rates above 100 percent when other taxes
are incorporated – effectively requiring people to
pay rather than be paid to work, earn business income, or sell capital assets. We previously
found
that an extremely aggressive package of tax hikes on high earners,
corporations, and the financial sector might cover one-third of the $30
trillion cost of Medicare for All. Our very rough estimates showed that
over the next decade raising the top two individual and pass-through
rates to 70 percent would raise about $2 trillion, phasing out most tax
breaks for higher earners (assuming that 70 percent top rate) could very
generously raise another $2 trillion, and doubling the corporate tax
rate would raise $2 trillion. We also found that a wealth tax or
“mark-to-market” capital gains taxation could raise $3 trillion, and the
combination of a financial transaction tax and a tax on large financial
institutions could raise about $1 trillion. Other taxes on high earners
and the wealthy could raise some additional funds.
Enact a combination of approaches. Rather
than identify a single revenue source to finance Medicare for All,
policymakers could combine several options. For example, one could
combine a 16 percent employer-side payroll tax with a public premium
averaging $3,000 per capita, $5 trillion of taxes on high earners and
corporations, and $1 trillion of spending cuts. Other small options,
such as a higher excise taxes on alcohol, tobacco, or sugary drinks,
could also be included, as could policies to require or encourage state
governments to contribute to offsetting the cost of Medicare for All. Adopting smaller versions of several policies may prove more viable than adopting any one policy in full.
While the financing options above are quite large in magnitude, they
could be reduced significantly by reducing the cost of Medicare for All
itself.
These cost reductions could be achieved in part by reforming or
reducing provider payments, improving care coordination, and identifying
policies to reduce excessive utilization of care. Our
Budget Offsets Bank
incudes numerous options to reduce the cost of traditional Medicare;
some of these options would save much more if applied to a comprehensive
Medicare for All program.
Cost reductions could also be achieved by scaling back the generosity
of a Medicare for All program. For example, the Urban Institute
recently
estimated
that a Medicare for All plan that required cost sharing to cover
between 5 and 20 percent of medical costs (depending on income) and
covered only core health benefits (not vision, dental, hearing, or
long-term services and supports) would cost the federal government half
as much per person as a comprehensive Medicare for All plan. A $15
trillion cost could be financed with a 15 percent payroll tax, as
compared to the 32 percent payroll tax required to fund $30 trillion.
Choices and Trade-Offs in Financing Medicare for All
Deciding how to finance Medicare for All involves weighing
significant trade-offs amongst options as well as relative to the
current system. Indeed, the design of Medicare for All financing may
have as much distributional, economic, and policy importance as the
adoption of Medicare for All itself.
While many Americans are enrolled in heavily subsidized Medicare,
Medicaid, or private insurance plans, the majority of Americans pay for
their health care through premiums (especially employer-paid premiums),
deductibles, copayments, and coinsurance.
While premiums and cost sharing are not a form of taxation, they do
share some features in common with a “head tax” – a fixed-dollar tax
imposed on every person. For those with employer-provided health
insurance especially, premiums generally remain fixed regardless of
changes in income. Like head taxes, insurance premiums would thus be
regressive if measured relative to income among those who pay them
(though many of the lowest earners on Medicaid or receiving exchange
subsidies pay little or no premiums). Also like a head tax, premiums are
economically efficient in the sense that they create very little
economic distortion and do not generally disincentivize more work,
investment, or productivity. Finally, because premiums and cost sharing
don’t affect marginal tax rates or returns to work and investment, they
have little effect on the government’s ability to raise revenue.
Any plan to replace current premiums and cost sharing must weigh how
the new finance scheme will impact income distribution, economic output,
and tax capacity. In the coming months, the Committee for a Responsible
Federal Budget will release a full report evaluating the various
effects of most of the options mentioned in this paper.
From a distributional standpoint, most of the options we put forward
above would be more progressive on average than current law, though the
impact would vary person to person and many of the options would
represent a cost increase for lower-income individuals and families who
currently benefit from Medicaid and exchange subsidies. Options would
differ in their distributional impact. To get a broad sense of how
distribution may differ,
a recent CBO study
shows that in 2016 the top income quintile (indirectly) paid less than
40 percent of employer-side health premiums, but they paid more than 85
percent of individual and corporate income taxes and would have paid
over 50 percent of a new flat payroll tax. The top percentile paid about
2 percent of premiums, but they paid over 40 percent of income taxes
and would have paid 10 percent of a new flat payroll tax.
At the same time, most of the options we present would shrink the
economy compared to the current system. The 32 percent payroll tax hike,
for example, would increase the effective marginal tax rate on labor by
about 23 percent after accounting for various interactions. Penn
Wharton Budget Model recently
estimated that an 11.25 percent payroll tax increase used to pay for a Universal Basic Income (UBI) would reduce GDP by 1.7 percent.
6
This suggests that financing Medicare for All with a payroll tax would
shrink the size of the economy by about 3.5 percent by 2030 – though the
actual effect may differ. This economic impact would be the equivalent
of a $3,200 reduction in per-person income and would result in a 6.5
percent reduction in hours worked – a 9 million person reduction in
full-time equivalent (FTE) workers in 2030.
Deficit-financing Medicare for All would be far more damaging to the
economy. Assuming that such a massive increase in the debt would not
roil financial markets or lead to high inflation, we estimate that a 108
percent of GDP increase in the federal debt would shrink the size of
the economy by roughly 5 percent in 2030 – the equivalent of a $4,500
reduction in per-person income – and far more in the following years.
This is a low-end estimate of economic impact because it implicitly
assumes few limits on the amount of foreign savings available to
purchase Treasury bonds. Because deficit-financing would have little
direct impact on the incentive to work, we estimate a 0.7 percent or 1
million FTE reduction in work hours by 2030.
An additional consideration is how much tax capacity any of these
financing options might leave for future policymakers aiming to raise
revenue to pay for new programs, fund existing ones, or reduce deficits.
The best economic literature suggests a revenue-maximizing tax rate of
between 63 and 73 percent,
7 after which further rate increases actually
lose revenue. Tax rates approaching these high levels would reduce the ability of policymakers to raise revenue in the future.
Under current law, the top effective marginal tax rate (accounting
for state and local taxes in a typical state) is about 48 percent. That
rate would rise to 69 percent after a 32 percent payroll tax hike (the
increase is smaller than the tax due to interactions with the tax base),
73 percent after a 25 percent income surtax, and 85 percent if income
tax rates were doubled. In other words, each of these options would
bring the top rate close to or above the revenue-maximizing rate.
Conclusion
Regardless of its impact on national health expenditures, Medicare
for All would shift substantial costs from the private sector to the
federal government. By most estimates, a comprehensive Medicare for All
plan that expands coverage to every U.S. resident for nearly all medical
services and eliminates premiums and cost sharing would cost the
federal government roughly $30 trillion over a decade.
Policymakers have a number of options available to finance the $30
trillion cost of Medicare for All, but each option would come with its
own set of trade-offs.
In this preliminary analysis, we estimate the cost could be covered
with a 32 percent payroll tax, a 25 percent income surtax, a 42 percent
value-added tax, or a public premium averaging $7,500 per capita or more
than $12,000 per individual who wouldn’t otherwise be enrolled in
Medicare, Medicaid, or CHIP. Medicare for All could also be paid for by
more than doubling individual and corporate income tax rates, reducing
federal spending by 80 percent, or increasing the national debt by 108
percent of GDP. Tax increases on high earners, corporations, and the
financial sector by themselves could not cover much more than one-third
of the cost of Medicare for All.
Rather than adopting any one of the proposals above, policymakers
could also consider a combination of approaches to finance Medicare for
All
. Reducing the cost, scope, or generosity of Medicare for All would also reduce the magnitude of needed financing.
In deciding how to finance Medicare for All
, policymakers
must consider the distributional, economic, and policy consequences of
replacing premiums and cost sharing with various alternatives. Most of
the options we put forward are more progressive on average than current
law but would shrink economic output and bring the top tax rate up to
its revenue-maximizing level – leaving little capacity for further
taxes.
This paper will be followed by a more detailed analysis of the various consequences of different financing options.
1
These figures represent rough estimates generated by the Committee for a
Responsible Federal Budget using our own models as well as a variety of
sources, including the
Open Source Policy Center’s Tax Brain, the
Congressional Budget Office, the
Joint Committee on Taxation, the
Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, and the
Tax Policy Center.
Estimates are from 2021 to 2030, exclude any macroeconomic effects, and
include only modest behavioral effects. All estimates assume that the
elimination of private health insurance premiums would lead to a
significant increase in taxable wages.
2
An employer-side payroll tax raises significantly less than an
employee-side tax because higher employer contributions lead them to pay
lower taxable wages. The result is lower revenue from current income
and payroll taxes as well as from the newly imposed payroll tax itself.
3
As part of this policy, we also assume all capital gains would be taxed
at death and with this surtax. Absent that assumption, capital gains
revenue would significantly
decline under this surtax.
4
Allowing households to deduct 20 percent of business income and step-up
the basis of assets held at death would require much higher rates and
would likely result in substantial tax avoidance. We therefore assume
any reasonable policy to increase tax rates so dramatically would close
off these and other avoidance techniques that could lead to large
revenue losses.
5
The replacement of Medicare, Medicaid, and most other federal health
spending is already assumed in cost estimates of Medicare for All. If
the cost of the new Medicare for All program were cut proportionally
with the rest of the budget, the total size of the cut would fall to 45
percent.
6
A payroll-tax-financed UBI should be economically similar to a payroll
tax financed Medicare for All, as both essentially raise the payroll tax
to finance a lump-sum payment.
7 Economists Mathias Trabandt and Harold Uhlig
estimate a revenue-maximizing rate of 63 percent, while economists Peter Diamond and Emmanuel Saez
estimate a revenue-maximizing rate of 73 percent.